The authors thank Holger Moeller for the previous e-letter. As he
noticed, there is a typographical error in the number related to attributable
deaths in New Zealand. The correct number is 8 per 100,000.
Professor Boddewyn’s reply is interesting for what it admits and
omits.
He admits that the International Advertising Association (IAA)
reports published in 1983 and 1986 were based on his editing of “the draft
paper written by Paul Bingham [of British American Tobacco].” To my
knowledge, there has been no such public admission previously by Professor
Boddewyn, BAT, or IAA in the 20+ years since publication of tho...
Professor Boddewyn’s reply is interesting for what it admits and
omits.
He admits that the International Advertising Association (IAA)
reports published in 1983 and 1986 were based on his editing of “the draft
paper written by Paul Bingham [of British American Tobacco].” To my
knowledge, there has been no such public admission previously by Professor
Boddewyn, BAT, or IAA in the 20+ years since publication of those reports.
However, Boddewyn omits an explanation as to why his name appeared
prominently on the cover of the IAA reports (see the image of the 1983
cover in my paper in Tobacco Control) and as the author of the “Editor’s
Introduction,” but Bingham’s name was nowhere to be seen in the entirety
of both documents.
He explains that “I did reveal from the start that my 1983 and 1986
reports were ‘prepared by and from industry sources, using data from
official and trade organizations.’” I acknowledged that disclosure in my
paper, but I added the following:
“However, the report provides no further information on who conducted
the analyses and wrote the text. Thus, the IAA publication links the
16–country study to the IAA itself, to Boddewyn and to ‘industry sources’,
but it is unclear whether ‘industry’ refers to the advertising or tobacco
industry.”
Boddewyn continues to obscure or ignore Bingham’s role in
ghost–writing the reports when he refers to “MY 1983 and 1986 reports”
(emphasis added).
Boddewyn claims that “MY reports on the impact of advertising bans on
tobacco consumption ... provided much needed information about this issue
at the time” (emphasis added). He omits any response to the comments in my
paper about a key flaw in the analyses by IAA/Bingham—specifically, the
failure to take into account other controls on tobacco demand (besides
advertising) such as tobacco price or income. Because of that flaw, it
would be correct to state that the reports provided misinformation or
disinformation much needed by the tobacco industry.
Ronald M. Davis, MD
Director
Center for Health Promotion and Disease Prevention
What a pleasure to be cited for something I published 25 years ago!
It is, of course, less pleasant to be implicitly incriminated as being
some sort of a “paid hack” for the tobacco industry. Besides,
the intended harm has been done since the Editor did not have the academic
courtesy of asking me to reply to this personal attack in the same issue
where the article by R.M. Davis has appeared.
What a pleasure to be cited for something I published 25 years ago!
It is, of course, less pleasant to be implicitly incriminated as being
some sort of a “paid hack” for the tobacco industry. Besides,
the intended harm has been done since the Editor did not have the academic
courtesy of asking me to reply to this personal attack in the same issue
where the article by R.M. Davis has appeared.
In answering this charge, I must mostly rely on my memory because
moving to a new school building in 2001 and my retirement later on led me
to get rid of some 40 filing drawers of manuscripts and correspondence.
It appears to me that the whole issue of “ghost-writing”
revolves around what an editor does since Ronald Davis correctly states
that I wrote the Introduction and “edited” the 1983 and 1986
editions of Tobacco Advertising Bans and Consumption in 16 Countries, that
were published by the International Advertising Association. I know
editing very well since I served 35 years as Editor of International
Studies of Management & Organization. In such a position of
responsibility, you check the texts that will get your imprimatur in terms
of the facts used, the quality of the arguments, the clarity and flow of
the logic as well as the causal argumentation or, at least, the
plausibility and convincingness of the conclusion.
Was I qualified to do this job at the time? I think so because I
majored in Marketing as well as Business & Its Environment (the
precursor field to Business & Society) at the University of Washington
where I wrote my doctoral dissertation in 1964 on a topic combining
political science and marketing. Since then, I have extensively published
on business-government relations and public affairs, both domestically and
internationally.
That is why the International Advertising Association (IAA) asked me
in the late 1960s and again in the 1970s and 1980s to conduct some 15
studies of the regulation and self-regulation of advertising around the
world on such topics as advertising to children, food advertisings,
decency and sexism in advertisements, and pharmaceutical advertising. The
latter study was good enough to have the World Health Organization –
no less – to ask me to replicate it in 1987 (“Report on the
WHO Survey on Ethical Criteria for Drug Promotion”) shortly after my
1986 second report on tobacco-advertising bans. The WHO must not have
thought badly of me at that time! This is a very good proof of independent
research credibility, is it not?
In any case, when the IAA asked me to edit the draft paper written by
Paul Bingham (who claimed to have “ghost-written” the whole
report), I did what a competent editor should do – namely, meeting
with Paul Bingham in London in order to check on the credibility of his
sources which were almost exclusively government reports based on the
national collections of excise taxes and other records which everybody has
used in tobacco-control studies. I also corresponded with tobacco-industry
market researchers and legal experts in the United States, Sweden and
Switzerland in order to verify or understand various data, statistical
techniques and legal points – hence, for example, my correspondence
with Jean Besques of Philip Morris in Lausanne.
I will add that I found these exchanges with tobacco-industry people
very valuable in understanding their business-government and public-
affairs philosophy, strategies and tactics – one of my predominant
research interests since 1964 (see above).
I did reveal from the start that my 1983 and 1986 reports were
“prepared by and from industry sources, using data from official and
trade organizations.” I was compensated for my time or reimbursed
for my expenses by tobacco firms and associations but most tobacco-control
researchers or their employers are and have to be subsidized one way or
another by somebody. Twenty-five years ago, “Competing
Interests” notes such as the one by Ronald Davis (who received
released time which is as good as money) at the end of his article were
unknown. However, I did acknowledge this industry support in my written
statement to Congress in 1987 and 1989.
Mr. Davis appears to be incensed that my reports on the impact of
advertising bans on tobacco consumption were given and did receive ample
publicity but this happened because they provided much needed information
about this issue at the time. Of course, many factors bear on smoking
initiation, habits and consumption but his criticism of my work fails to
report that tobacco-advertising bans were heavily promoted by antismoking
champions in the early 1980s – otherwise, why would congressional
bodies in the United States, Canada and New Zealand (among other
countries) have held special hearings on tobacco-advertising bans? It was
not just a matter of determining their effects on smoking but also of
testing the constitutionality of restrictions on the freedom of commercial
speech.
If you do not believe me, read the pronouncements of a leading
antismoking advocate at the time, Dr. K. Bjartveit, then Chairman of
Norway’s National Council on Smoking and Health: “A cautious
conclusion would be that the advertising ban [in Norway], with the
concomitant publicity through the legislative process, had an impact on
consumption and young people’s smoking and in combination with
continued and increased educational efforts, was a causal factor in the
new trend (Results and Conclusion. Paper presented at the Seventh World
Conference on Smoking and Health. Perth, Australia: 3 April 1990, p. 8).
Getting my research on tobacco-advertising bans published took some
interesting twists. I first submitted my article that appeared in the
British Journal of Addiction to a leading journal in public-health
management (its exact title escapes me because of my now missing files).
It was promptly returned to me as “unsuitable” but, at the
time, I could have sworn I knew who (Michael Pertschuck?) wrote the
rejection letter because of the similarities of the Editor’s
arguments to what he had written or testified against me and other
researchers not of his persuasion. So much for airing controversial views
in antismoking publications!
This situation led me to write an article for the Journal of
Advertising in 1993 (22,4, pp. 105-107) on “Where Should Articles on
the Link Between Tobacco Advertising and Consumption Be Published?”
For example, why did the famous study of how young kids could remember Joe
Camel ads appear in the Journal of the American Medical Association (JAMA)
– of all places! – rather than in the Journal of Advertising
or the Journal of Advertising Research where reviewers would have been
competent to handle a fairly straightforward proposition about advertising
effects on young people? We could as well have medical articles appear in
the Journal of Marketing!
Altogether, I do not have any regret to have edited these IAA reports
because they forced antismoking researchers to acknowledge (as I did) that
factors other than tobacco-advertising bans – their bˆte noire at
the time – were at play. Ultimately, they had to urge that
everything related to tobacco production, distribution and consumption be
regulated, with tobacco-advertising bans relegated to a complementary
role.
Those were the not-so-strawmen against whom the IAA reports I
introduced and edited had to challenge. In the spirit of free inquiry,
this was a do-able and respectable endeavor for which no apology is
needed.
Jean J. Boddewyn
Emeritus Professor of Marketing & International Business
Baruch College (CUNY)
9 April 2008
In response to our piece cautioning about the use of the
‘precautionary principle’ in debates about setting emissions limits, Nigel
Gray writes that it has been around since the beginning of public health
activity and offers as examples ‘[taking] the precaution of hunting for
clean water on the grounds that doing nothing might allow epidemics of
cholera, typhoid and hookworm to continue’ and the introduction of polio
vac...
In response to our piece cautioning about the use of the
‘precautionary principle’ in debates about setting emissions limits, Nigel
Gray writes that it has been around since the beginning of public health
activity and offers as examples ‘[taking] the precaution of hunting for
clean water on the grounds that doing nothing might allow epidemics of
cholera, typhoid and hookworm to continue’ and the introduction of polio
vaccine ‘as a precautionary manoeuvre because a small percentage of those
infected developed clinical disease’. While these measures (and countless
other public health measures) have been taken for ‘precautionary’ reasons,
this does not mean that they were undertaken as an exercise of what is
today known as the ‘precautionary principle’.
The point we were making in our piece was that the ‘precautionary
principle’ has a commonly understood meaning – one that is being
misapplied in the debate about emissions limits. Framing matters deeply
to the resolution of policy debates. If the debate about setting emissions
limits continues without assertions that the ‘precautionary principle’
favours the setting of limits and without assumptions that the TobReg
proposal is a ‘precautionary’ one, we think the debate will be better for
it.
Regulation and precautions
Nigel Gray
April 11, 2008
Jonathon Lieberman worries about TobReg’s use of the precautionary
principle as justification for recommending reduction of toxicants in
cigarette emissions and suggests that the precautionary principle is a
1970’s development. I thought it had been around since the beginning of
Public Health activity when we took the precaution of hunting for clean
water on...
Regulation and precautions
Nigel Gray
April 11, 2008
Jonathon Lieberman worries about TobReg’s use of the precautionary
principle as justification for recommending reduction of toxicants in
cigarette emissions and suggests that the precautionary principle is a
1970’s development. I thought it had been around since the beginning of
Public Health activity when we took the precaution of hunting for clean
water on the grounds that doing nothing might allow epidemics of cholera,
typhoid and hookworm to continue. Similarly we introduced polio vaccine
as a precautionary manoeuvre because a small percentage of those infected
developed clinical disease. However debating the precautionary principle
takes us away from the intention behind TobReg’s proposals to reduce
toxicants in smoke.
In simple terms we face the choice of doing nothing, or doing
something that has a strong chance of doing good ( eg.,removing
nitrosamines). Doing nothing means accepting the status quo and allowing
the industry to add whatever they like to cigarettes. I think there are
good reasons for objecting to the status quo as we face developments like
the marketing of candy flavoured cigarettes, which will probably appeal to
teenagers but will also probably contain increased sugar content (burning
sugars gives rise to acetaldehyde) so adding them is indirectly increasing
the carcinogen content of the smoke. I am unable to see how anyone can
see this as OK. I can’t imagine anyone adding carcinogens to any normal
consumer product.
In other words I am in favour of regulation of smoke and find it hard
to understand those who favour the status quo. I haven’t heard anyone
objecting to the regulation of beer or strawberry jam but the multi-
toxicant cigarette smoke seems to be different, even though we regulate
everything about its use and marketing.
The argument against this regulation is that we might somehow make
things worse by taking toxicants out of the mixture. We put appropriate
caveats into our reasoning and the article because of this possibility
despite the fact that I personally see it as remote, although I am aware
of the historical observation (1) that some things have gone down and some
have gone up. TobReg’s recommendations should avoid this possibility
It has to be conceded that thinking up rational ways of regulating
smoke was exceptionally difficult simply because of the complexity of the
mixture. I am, however, quite proud of the approach taken which I see as
practical. It will, of course, be supported by monitoring – something we
never had resources to do in the past but which can be easily funded by
hypothecated taxation.
The observation driving my own interest in removing toxicants arises
from the following:
Based on US data (2).
• Tobacco consumption has declined
• Total lung cancer rates have declined (as expected)
• Squamous carcinoma rates have declined ( as expected)
• Adenocarcinoma rates increased ( NOT expected ) during the nineties
(they may be plateauing now)
The only reason I can think of for this observation is that the
recipes for modern US cigarettes became more adenocarcinogenic than they
had been. I think, since cigarettes will continue to be with us, that we
should simplify them a great deal and that to leave their emissions
unregulated would be negligent
Declaration of interest. The writer is a member of TobReg. This
letter, however, is personal and I take responsibility for the views
expressed
Reference List
1. King B, Borland R, Fowles J. Mainstream smoke emissions of
Australian and Canadian cigarettes. Nicotine.Tob.Res. 2007;9(8):835-44.
2. Thun MJ, Lally CA, Flannery JT, Calle EE, Flanders WD, Heath CWJ.
Cigarette smoking and changes in the histopathology of lung cancer.
J.Natl.Cancer Inst. 1997;89(21):1580-6.
The proposal by the World Health Organization Study Group on Tobacco
Product Regulation (TobReg) for the setting of limits on emissions of
certain toxicants in cigarette smoke (1) is certain to generate heated
debate. Product regulation remains the most fraught policy area in tobacco
control. In other areas, public health dictates are clear. Ongoing
contests tend to be primarily either ones of competi...
The proposal by the World Health Organization Study Group on Tobacco
Product Regulation (TobReg) for the setting of limits on emissions of
certain toxicants in cigarette smoke (1) is certain to generate heated
debate. Product regulation remains the most fraught policy area in tobacco
control. In other areas, public health dictates are clear. Ongoing
contests tend to be primarily either ones of competing values, political
will or the details of implementation. Regulation of cigarette smoke
emissions is fundamentally different. It is not clear how – or even if –
regulation can advance public health, and there are substantial risks in
getting things wrong.
In such circumstances, how does policy move forward? In its report,
TobReg asserts that its approach is “based on the well-accepted
precautionary approaches used in public health”, with known harmful
constituents of products to be reduced “to the extent technically
feasible” without need for “proof of a specific linkage between a lower
level (amount) of any individual constituent and a lower level of human
disease (response)”. Burns et al reiterate this point in their paper
describing the proposal.(2) They argue that, while “[e]xisting science does
not allow a definitive conclusion that reduction of nitrosamines, or any
other individual toxicants in cigarette smoke, will reduce cancer
incidence, or the rate of any other tobacco related disease, in smokers
who use cigarettes with lower levels of these toxicants”, TobReg’s
proposed strategy is “based on sound precautionary approaches of reducing
toxicant levels wherever possible”. In papers that question the wisdom of
setting emissions limits, Chapman and Hammond et al nevertheless accept
that the approach enjoys the support of the “precautionary principle”.(3,4)
RISKS OF THE TOBREG PROPOSAL
Neither TobReg’s report nor the Burns et al paper elide the risks of
the TobReg proposal. TobReg, acutely aware of the history of consumers
being misled by the use of machine testing for tar and nicotine yields,
recommends that regulation prohibit use of results from the proposed
testing in marketing or other communications with consumers, including on
labelling, and that manufacturers “be prohibited from making statements
that a brand has met governmental regulatory standards, and from
publicizing the relative ranking of brands by testing levels”. Regulators
will need “to monitor the understanding of the consumer about the
regulatory approaches undertaken” and “should pursue whatever corrective
action is necessary to prevent consumers from being misled”. TobReg also
acknowledges the risk that “changes in cigarette design and manufacturing
implemented to lower the regulated toxicants may have the effect of
increasing the levels of other non-regulated toxicants” and offers
proposals for monitoring for such unintended consequences.
While TobReg does not elide the risks, it nonetheless argues for
regulatory action. Others are less sanguine about the possibility of
overcoming the risks. Chapman envisages tobacco industry PR machines going
“into overdrive, spinning the changes in ways designed to comfort smokers
and risking another major era of consumer disinformation”. He anticipates
“a simple and misleading message by the media that the newly regulated
products are now ‘safer’”.
Kozlowski is understandably sceptical of the capacity of regulators
to monitor and correct consumer perceptions.(5) In the modern world of news
reports, editorials and blogs, “[s]uch power would be the unrealizable
dreams of the most powerful, paternalistic totalitarian state”. Both
Chapman and Hammond et al refer also to the critical issue of resources
required to introduce and monitor emissions limits.
THE PRECAUTIONARY PRINCIPLE
If TobReg is not sure that its proposed approach will have any public
health benefit – it describes reduction in the incidence of cancer and
other tobacco related disease in smokers who use cigarettes with lower
levels of the regulated toxicants as a “hoped for outcome” – and if all
acknowledge that it carries major risks and costs, an obvious question
emerges. How could the regulatory precept known as the “precautionary
principle” militate in favour of the proposed approach?
The precautionary principle emerged in the mid-1970s with the rise of
environmentalism in Germany. It has since been widely invoked, including
in a number of international environmental agreements,(6,7,8, 9,10,11)and
defined in a range of different ways.(12,13) The most often referenced
definition is that in the Rio Declaration on Environment and Development,(7)
which states that: “Where there are threats of serious or irreversible
damage, lack of full scientific certainty shall not be used as a reason
for postponing cost-effective measures to prevent environmental
degradation”. This understanding, mirrored in the United Nations Framework
Convention on Climate Change(8) and the earlier Ministerial Declaration of
the Second International Conference on the Protection of the North Sea,(14)
is well accepted and unobjectionable. It suggests “that a lack of decisive
evidence of harm should not be a ground for refusing to regulate”;(12) and
“that regulatory policy should seek to prevent harm before it occurs, and
that it should reject the insistence of regulatory targets that a never-
ending quest for improved information should indefinitely postpone
sensible regulatory measures”.(15)
However, attempts to take the precautionary principle further, and
cast it as offering substantive prescriptive guidance on what steps
regulators should take – as opposed to a reminder that, in certain
circumstances, they should not refrain from taking steps solely because of
scientific uncertainty – have been strongly critiqued. Sunstein argues
persuasively that the fundamental problem with prescriptive invocations of
the precautionary principle is that they are paralysing.12 Because risks
exist on all sides of social situations, the precautionary principle
offers no guidance – “it forbids all courses of action, including
regulation. It bans the very steps that it requires”.
In contrast to the belief often held that the precautionary principle
provides regulators with decision-making guidance, Sunstein argues that it
“becomes operational if and only if those who apply it wear blinders –
only, that is, if they focus on some aspects of the regulatory situation
but downplay or disregard others”. Sunstein suggests that invocation of
the precautionary principle can mask neglect of the systemic effect of
regulatory interventions: people tend to fixate on isolated problems and
fail to see the complex, system-wide effects of measures to address them.
The guidance provided by the principle, interpreted as applying
prescriptively, is illusory: “There are simply too many risks against
which one might take precautions. Precautions cannot be taken against all
risks … because efforts to redress any set of risks might produce risks of
their own”.
Sunstein’s view that the prescriptive version of the precautionary
principle is paralysing is echoed by Cross, who argues that if
“environmental and public health regulations frequently produce health or
other environmental harms, the basis for the precautionary principle
collapses”, as the principle itself would counsel against adopting such
regulations.(16) Cross notes that because “[f]ocusing great precaution upon
the instant problem must reduce precaution upon other problems, which may
prove greater and more serious”, the principle skews prioritisation of
government efforts to reduce risk. He also suggests that there are
significant risks from the societal economic costs of regulation, so that
reliance on the precautionary principle in situations where there is
little evidence of realisable health benefits from regulation “could cause
more health harm than it prevents”.
A CAUTIOUS APPROACH
The TobReg proposal is universally acknowledged to carry substantial
risks. TobReg itself acknowledges the risks and appears no more than
hopeful that its proposal might yield public health benefits. Yet the
proposal has somehow come to be accepted to embody a “precautionary”
approach. An examination of the meaning and use of the “precautionary
principle” sheds light on this confusion. The TobReg approach can only be
described as “precautionary” if the principle is not used in its
traditional sense (if it is used as offering prescriptive guidance rather
than arguing against the postponement of action) and if a highly selective
application of that contested version is invoked (one made through the
wearing of Sunstein’s “blinders”).
This is an area in which arguments have been, and will continue to be,
made on both sides. Those who argue in favour of setting emissions limits
are judging that the benefits of such an approach outweigh the risks and
the costs. But it is hard to see how their approach can be regarded as
more “precautionary” than that of those who argue against setting limits.
As we have argued, application of the precautionary principle as
offering any prescriptive guidance in favour of the TobReg proposal is
misguided. As the debate continues, we suggest that the precautionary
principle not be invoked in support of the setting of emissions limits.
Both Chapman and Hammond et al, after deferring to TobReg’s
“precautionary” framing, bring the issues back to their correct regulatory
framing – a weighing of benefits, risks and costs on the basis of the best
available evidence. This is the context in which the debate about
emissions limits should continue, without the precautionary principle
being misapplied to ease the burden of those making the case for emissions
limits.
REFERENCES
1. WHO Study Group on Tobacco Product Regulation (TobReg). The
scientific basis of tobacco product regulation: report of a WHO study
group. Geneva, Switzerland: World Health Organization, 2007.
2. Burns D, Dybing E, Gray N, et al. Mandated lowering of toxicants in
cigarette smoke: a description of the WHO TobReg proposal. Tob Control
2008;17:132-41.
3. Chapman S. Benefits and risks in ending regulatory exceptionalism for
tobacco. Tob Control 2008;17:73-4.
4. Hammond D, Wiebel F, Kozlowski L, et al. Revising the machine smoking
regime for cigarette emissions: implications for tobacco control policy.
Tob Control 2007;16:8-14.
5. Kozlowski L. The proposed tobacco regulation: the triumph of hope over
experience?. Tob Control 2008;17:74-5.
6. Montreal Protocol on Substances that Deplete the Ozone Layer (opened
for signature 16 September 1987, 1522 UNTS 3 (entered into force 1 January
1989) (Preamble)).
7. Rio Declaration on Environment and Development (UN Doc A/CONF.151/26
(vol I) (1992) (Principle 15)).
8. United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (opened for
signature 4 June 1992, 1771 UNTS 107 (entered into force 21 March 1994)
(Article 3(3))).
9. Treaty on European Union (Maastricht Treaty) (opened for signature 7
February 1992, [1992] OJ C 224, 1 (entered into force 1 November 1993)
(Article 130r(2))).
10. Cartagena Protocol on Biosafety to the Convention on Biological
Diversity (opened for signature 15 May 2000, 39 ILM 1027 (entered into
force 11 September 2003) (Article 1)).
11. Stockholm Convention on Persistent Organic Pollutants (opened for
signature 23 May 2001, 40 ILM 532 (entered into force 17 May 2004)
(Article 1).
12. Sunstein C. Laws of fear: beyond the precautionary principle.
Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 2005.
13. Morris J. Defining the precautionary principle. In Morris J, ed.
Rethinking risk and the precautionary principle. Oxford, UK: Butterworth-
Heinemann, 2000.
14. Ministerial Declaration for the Second International Conference on the
Protection of the North Sea (London, 25 November 1987).
15. Percival R. Who’s afraid of the precautionary principle?. Pace
Environmental Law Review 2005-2006:23;21-81.
16. Cross F. Paradoxical perils of the precautionary principle. Washington
and Lee Law Review 1996:53;851-925.
Dear Simon and Becky,
As a fellow advocate of non smoking I would like to congratulate you on
the Article: Markers of the demormalisation of smoking and the tobacco
industry. I note with interest your comments under the heading Smoking
rooms at airports.
You note "In early 2007, these uninviting rooms were quietly removed from
Australian airports...."
The Darwin International Airport still provides a room for the (many)...
Dear Simon and Becky,
As a fellow advocate of non smoking I would like to congratulate you on
the Article: Markers of the demormalisation of smoking and the tobacco
industry. I note with interest your comments under the heading Smoking
rooms at airports.
You note "In early 2007, these uninviting rooms were quietly removed from
Australian airports...."
The Darwin International Airport still provides a room for the (many)
smokers in the NT. The room conveniently opens directly on to the airport
waiting lounge, provides seating and a "view". Each time the door is
opened, a great waft of smoke-laden air rushes into the waiting area for
the rest of the potential passengers and visitors to inhale; and waiting
times can be long in Darwin with many of us waiting for 2am and later
flights.
Now we know the Northern Territory is different to the rest of Australia!
We also have a large group of smokers, and the indigenous territorians
smoke at high levels, in some communties 72% of all adults.
The Darwin Airport has not quietly removed the smoking room.
Yes we are different!
Regards
JMcDonald
Public Health Project Officer
Northern Territory
Australia
In a recently published article in Tobacco Control, Vander Beken and
colleagues [1] concluded that the Belgian cigarette black-market
manifested myriad links with the legitimate business world and, as a
result, effective tobacco control policies will need to address the role
of legitimate businesses in this market. Our letter confirms this
conclusion within a Canadian context.
In a recently published article in Tobacco Control, Vander Beken and
colleagues [1] concluded that the Belgian cigarette black-market
manifested myriad links with the legitimate business world and, as a
result, effective tobacco control policies will need to address the role
of legitimate businesses in this market. Our letter confirms this
conclusion within a Canadian context.
Approximately 10-17% of cigarettes smoked in Canada in 2005-2006 were
illicit, and 95% of all illicit cigarettes (i.e., contraband) in Canada
were manufactured on First Nations reserves in the provinces of Ontario
and Québec [2,3]. Even though two-thirds of contraband cigarette consumers
report buying contraband cigarettes at off-reserve locations [4], little
is known about the distribution network of contraband cigarettes in
Canada.
Previously, we examined the contraband cigarette market at one of
Canada's largest psychiatric hospitals, a 436-bed facility located in
Toronto [5]. Approximately 60% of the cigarette butts sampled from patient
ashtrays appeared to be contraband; and 80% of the cigarette packages
found in a facility-wide garbage audit at the psychiatric hospital were
from illicit brands manufactured on American Indian reservations in
northern New York State. Anecdotal evidence suggested that independent
convenience stores were serving as a prominent distribution source for
native-manufactured contraband cigarettes, and the current letter examined
this possibility.
We assessed the prevalence of legitimate independent convenience
stores willing to sell illicit native-manufactured cigarettes in Toronto,
Ontario. A list of all independent convenience store tobacco retailers in
the study area was obtained from the City of Toronto. Our sample included
all of the 115 independent convenience stores located within a 2 km
distance from the psychiatric hospital: 30 within 1 km, and 85 within the
1-2 km span. Data collection occurred during July and August 2007. A male
research assistant (aged 36 years) entered each of the 115 stores and
asked the clerk, "Do you have any native cigarettes?" A store was coded
as willing to sell illicit native cigarettes, if: (1) the clerk provided
an affirmative answer; (2) the clerk engaged the research assistant in a
selling transaction (e.g., the clerk asked the research assistant, "How
much money do you have?"); or (3) the research assistant saw the clerk
selling illicit native-manufactured cigarettes to another customer.
Legitimate independent convenience stores located closer to the
psychiatric hospital were significantly more likely to be willing to sell
illicit native-manufactured cigarettes. Approximately 57% (17/30) of the
stores within 1 km of the hospital were willing to sell contraband
cigarettes, while roughly 12% (10/85) of the stores located in the 1-2 km
zone showed the same tendency (chi-square = 24.9, p < 0.001).
Similar to the findings of Vander Beken, et al. 2008, our results
suggest that Ontario tobacco-control policies will need to recognize
legitimate businesses—in our case, independent convenience stores—as
important sources in the distribution network of black-market cigarettes.
References:
1. T Vander Beken, J Janssens, K Verpoest, A Balcaen, and F Vander
Laenen. Crossing geographical, legal and moral boundaries: The Belgian
cigarette black market. Tobacco Control 2008; 17:60-65.
2. Physicians for a Smoke-Free Canada. Warning signs about cigarette
smuggling: And actions governments can take to address this growing
problem. Ottawa: Physicians for a Smoke-Free Canada; 2006 December.
3. Imperial Tobacco. Collateral damage: Illicit tobacco trade takes
on phenomenal proportions. 2006 [cited 2007 February 5th]; Available
from:
http://www.imperialtobacco.com/onewebca/sites/IMP_5TUJVZ.nsf/vwPagesWebLive/362441A11150B0B6C1257108005E76AC?opendocument&DTC=&SID=
4. GFK Research Dynamics. New Information on Illegal Tobacco Sales:
National Study for the Canadian Tobacco Manufacturers' Council.
Mississauga, ON: Imperial Tobacco; 2007 July.
5. RC Callaghan, J Tavares, and L Taylor. Illicit cigarette markets
in marginalized, low-income populations: an example from psychiatric
patients in Toronto, Ontario. American Journal of Public Health 2008; 98:4
-5.
Readers of our paper Markers of the Denormalisation of Smoking and
the Tobacco Industry may be perplexed about the way the Abstract is
structured with the traditional Background, Methods, Results and
Conclusion headings. These headings were inserted during the editing
process after we as authors had approved the proofs of the paper. The
paper we approved had an unstructured abstract as was appropriate to a
paper of thi...
Readers of our paper Markers of the Denormalisation of Smoking and
the Tobacco Industry may be perplexed about the way the Abstract is
structured with the traditional Background, Methods, Results and
Conclusion headings. These headings were inserted during the editing
process after we as authors had approved the proofs of the paper. The
paper we approved had an unstructured abstract as was appropriate to a
paper of this sort.
We do not believe the error warrants a formal correction, but wanted
readers to understand how the oddity occurred.
The authors thank Holger Moeller for the previous e-letter. As he noticed, there is a typographical error in the number related to attributable deaths in New Zealand. The correct number is 8 per 100,000.
I think the rate for New Zealand in the discussion was meant to be 8 per 100,000 and not 8 per 10,000 which would be rather high.
Professor Boddewyn’s reply is interesting for what it admits and omits.
He admits that the International Advertising Association (IAA) reports published in 1983 and 1986 were based on his editing of “the draft paper written by Paul Bingham [of British American Tobacco].” To my knowledge, there has been no such public admission previously by Professor Boddewyn, BAT, or IAA in the 20+ years since publication of tho...
What a pleasure to be cited for something I published 25 years ago! It is, of course, less pleasant to be implicitly incriminated as being some sort of a “paid hack” for the tobacco industry. Besides, the intended harm has been done since the Editor did not have the academic courtesy of asking me to reply to this personal attack in the same issue where the article by R.M. Davis has appeared.
In answering this ch...
In response to our piece cautioning about the use of the ‘precautionary principle’ in debates about setting emissions limits, Nigel Gray writes that it has been around since the beginning of public health activity and offers as examples ‘[taking] the precaution of hunting for clean water on the grounds that doing nothing might allow epidemics of cholera, typhoid and hookworm to continue’ and the introduction of polio vac...
Regulation and precautions Nigel Gray April 11, 2008
Jonathon Lieberman worries about TobReg’s use of the precautionary principle as justification for recommending reduction of toxicants in cigarette emissions and suggests that the precautionary principle is a 1970’s development. I thought it had been around since the beginning of Public Health activity when we took the precaution of hunting for clean water on...
BACKGROUND
The proposal by the World Health Organization Study Group on Tobacco Product Regulation (TobReg) for the setting of limits on emissions of certain toxicants in cigarette smoke (1) is certain to generate heated debate. Product regulation remains the most fraught policy area in tobacco control. In other areas, public health dictates are clear. Ongoing contests tend to be primarily either ones of competi...
Dear Simon and Becky, As a fellow advocate of non smoking I would like to congratulate you on the Article: Markers of the demormalisation of smoking and the tobacco industry. I note with interest your comments under the heading Smoking rooms at airports. You note "In early 2007, these uninviting rooms were quietly removed from Australian airports...." The Darwin International Airport still provides a room for the (many)...
In a recently published article in Tobacco Control, Vander Beken and colleagues [1] concluded that the Belgian cigarette black-market manifested myriad links with the legitimate business world and, as a result, effective tobacco control policies will need to address the role of legitimate businesses in this market. Our letter confirms this conclusion within a Canadian context.
Approximately 10-17% of cigarettes...
Readers of our paper Markers of the Denormalisation of Smoking and the Tobacco Industry may be perplexed about the way the Abstract is structured with the traditional Background, Methods, Results and Conclusion headings. These headings were inserted during the editing process after we as authors had approved the proofs of the paper. The paper we approved had an unstructured abstract as was appropriate to a paper of thi...
Pages